Sunday, June 02, 2013

Chairman Ben S. Bernanke - At the Baccalaureate Ceremony at Princeton University, Princeton, New Jersey

The Ten Suggestions
It's nice to be back at Princeton. I find it difficult to believe that it's been almost 11 years since I departed these halls for Washington. I wrote recently to inquire about the status of my leave from the university, and the letter I got back began, "Regrettably, Princeton receives many more qualified applicants for faculty positions than we can accommodate."1          I'll extend my best wishes to the seniors later, but first I want to congratulate the parents and families here. As a parent myself, I know that putting your kid through college these days is no walk in the park. Some years ago I had a colleague who sent three kids through Princeton even though neither he nor his wife attended this university. He and his spouse were very proud of that accomplishment, as they should have been. But my colleague also used to say that, from a financial perspective, the experience was like buying a new Cadillac every year and then driving it off a cliff. I should say that he always added that he would do it all over again in a minute. So, well done, moms, dads, and families.
   
This is indeed an impressive and appropriate setting for a commencement. I am sure that, from this lectern, any number of distinguished spiritual leaders have ruminated on the lessons of the Ten Commandments. I don't have that kind of confidence, and, anyway, coveting your neighbor's ox or donkey is not the problem it used to be, so I thought I would use my few minutes today to make Ten Suggestions, or maybe just Ten Observations, about the world and your lives after Princeton. Please note, these points have nothing whatsoever to do with interest rates. My qualification for making such suggestions, or observations, besides having kindly been invited to speak today by President Tilghman, is the same as the reason that your obnoxious brother or sister got to go to bed later--I am older than you. All of what follows has been road-tested in real-life situations, but past performance is no guarantee of future results.
   
1. The poet Robert Burns once said something about the best-laid plans of mice and men ganging aft agley, whatever "agley" means. A more contemporary philosopher, Forrest Gump, said something similar about life and boxes of chocolates and not knowing what you are going to get. They were both right. Life is amazingly unpredictable; any 22-year-old who thinks he or she knows where they will be in 10 years, much less in 30, is simply lacking imagination. Look what happened to me: A dozen years ago I was minding my own business teaching Economics 101 in Alexander Hall and trying to think of good excuses for avoiding faculty meetings. Then I got a phone call . . . In case you are skeptical of Forrest Gump's insight, here's a concrete suggestion for each of the graduating seniors. Take a few minutes the first chance you get and talk to an alum participating in his or her 25th, or 30th, or 40th reunion--you know, somebody who was near the front of the P-rade. Ask them, back when they were graduating 25, 30, or 40 years ago, where they expected to be today. If you can get them to open up, they will tell you that today they are happy and satisfied in various measures, or not, and their personal stories will be filled with highs and lows and in-betweens. But, I am willing to bet, those life stories will in almost all cases be quite different, in large and small ways, from what they expected when they started out. This is a good thing, not a bad thing; who wants to know the end of a story that's only in its early chapters? Don't be afraid to let the drama play out.
   
2. Does the fact that our lives are so influenced by chance and seemingly small decisions and actions mean that there is no point to planning, to striving? Not at all. Whatever life may have in store for you, each of you has a grand, lifelong project, and that is the development of yourself as a human being. Your family and friends and your time at Princeton have given you a good start. What will you do with it? Will you keep learning and thinking hard and critically about the most important questions? Will you become an emotionally stronger person, more generous, more loving, more ethical? Will you involve yourself actively and constructively in the world? Many things will happen in your lives, pleasant and not so pleasant, but, paraphrasing a Woodrow Wilson School adage from the time I was here, "Wherever you go, there you are." If you are not happy with yourself, even the loftiest achievements won't bring you much satisfaction.
   
3. The concept of success leads me to consider so-called meritocracies and their implications. We have been taught that meritocratic institutions and societies are fair. Putting aside the reality that no system, including our own, is really entirely meritocratic, meritocracies may be fairer and more efficient than some alternatives. But fair in an absolute sense? Think about it. A meritocracy is a system in which the people who are the luckiest in their health and genetic endowment; luckiest in terms of family support, encouragement, and, probably, income; luckiest in their educational and career opportunities; and luckiest in so many other ways difficult to enumerate--these are the folks who reap the largest rewards. The only way for even a putative meritocracy to hope to pass ethical muster, to be considered fair, is if those who are the luckiest in all of those respects also have the greatest responsibility to work hard, to contribute to the betterment of the world, and to share their luck with others. As the Gospel of Luke says (and I am sure my rabbi will forgive me for quoting the New Testament in a good cause): "From everyone to whom much has been given, much will be required; and from the one to whom much has been entrusted, even more will be demanded" (Luke 12:48, New Revised Standard Version Bible). Kind of grading on the curve, you might say.
    
4. Who is worthy of admiration? The admonition from Luke--which is shared by most ethical and philosophical traditions, by the way--helps with this question as well. Those most worthy of admiration are those who have made the best use of their advantages or, alternatively, coped most courageously with their adversities. I think most of us would agree that people who have, say, little formal schooling but labor honestly and diligently to help feed, clothe, and educate their families are deserving of greater respect--and help, if necessary--than many people who are superficially more successful. They're more fun to have a beer with, too. That's all that I know about sociology.
    
5. Since I have covered what I know about sociology, I might as well say something about political science as well. In regard to politics, I have always liked Lily Tomlin's line, in paraphrase: "I try to be cynical, but I just can't keep up." We all feel that way sometime. Actually, having been in Washington now for almost 11 years, as I mentioned, I feel that way quite a bit. Ultimately, though, cynicism is a poor substitute for critical thought and constructive action. Sure, interests and money and ideology all matter, as you learned in political science. But my experience is that most of our politicians and policymakers are trying to do the right thing, according to their own views and consciences, most of the time. If you think that the bad or indifferent results that too often come out of Washington are due to base motives and bad intentions, you are giving politicians and policymakers way too much credit for being effective. Honest error in the face of complex and possibly intractable problems is a far more important source of bad results than are bad motives. For these reasons, the greatest forces in Washington are ideas, and people prepared to act on those ideas. Public service isn't easy. But, in the end, if you are inclined in that direction, it is a worthy and challenging pursuit.
   
6. Having taken a stab at sociology and political science, let me wrap up economics while I'm at it. Economics is a highly sophisticated field of thought that is superb at explaining to policymakers precisely why the choices they made in the past were wrong. About the future, not so much. However, careful economic analysis does have one important benefit, which is that it can help kill ideas that are completely logically inconsistent or wildly at variance with the data. This insight covers at least 90 percent of proposed economic policies.
   
7. I'm not going to tell you that money doesn't matter, because you wouldn't believe me anyway. In fact, for too many people around the world, money is literally a life-or-death proposition. But if you are part of the lucky minority with the ability to choose, remember that money is a means, not an end. A career decision based only on money and not on love of the work or a desire to make a difference is a recipe for unhappiness.
   
8. Nobody likes to fail but failure is an essential part of life and of learning. If your uniform isn't dirty, you haven't been in the game.
   
9. I spoke earlier about definitions of personal success in an unpredictable world. I hope that as you develop your own definition of success, you will be able to do so, if you wish, with a close companion on your journey. In making that choice, remember that physical beauty is evolution's way of assuring us that the other person doesn't have too many intestinal parasites. Don't get me wrong, I am all for beauty, romance, and sexual attraction--where would Hollywood and Madison Avenue be without them? But while important, those are not the only things to look for in a partner. The two of you will have a long trip together, I hope, and you will need each other's support and sympathy more times than you can count. Speaking as somebody who has been happily married for 35 years, I can't imagine any choice more consequential for a lifelong journey than the choice of a traveling companion.
   
10. Call your mom and dad once in a while. A time will come when you will want your own grown-up, busy, hyper-successful children to call you. Also, remember who paid your tuition to Princeton.
   
Those are my suggestions. They're probably worth exactly what you paid for them. But they come from someone who shares your affection for this great institution and who wishes you the best for the future.
   
Congratulations, graduates. Give 'em hell.

--June 2, 2013------------------

1. Note to journalists: This is a joke. My leave from Princeton expired in 2005. Return to texto

Saturday, June 01, 2013

Tirar lições sobre o crescimento a partir da austeridade

 
Num recente conjunto de estudos, Carmen Reinhart e Kenneth Rogoff utilizaram uma vasta gama de dados históricos para mostrar que a acumulação de níveis elevados de dívida pública (e privada) relativamente ao produto interno bruto (PIB) tem um efeito negativo prolongado sobre o crescimento. A dimensão deste efeito desencadeou o debate sobre alguns erros de cálculo. Contudo, poucos duvidaram da validade deste padrão.
 
Isto não deverá ser surpreendente. Normalmente, a acumulação excessiva de dívida implica que alguma parte da procura agregada doméstica é adiantada, pelo que uma saída dessa dívida deve incluir mais poupanças e uma procura reduzida. O choque negativo tem um impacto adverso no sector não transaccionável, que é grande (aproximadamente dois terços de uma economia avançada) e totalmente dependente da procura doméstica. Como tal, as taxas de crescimento e do emprego caem durante o período de desalavacagem.

Numa economia aberta, a desalavancagem não prejudica, necessariamente, assim tanto o sector transaccionável. Mas, mesmo numa economia desse género, anos de procura interna dinamizada pela dívida pode produzir uma perda de competitividade e distorções estruturais. E a crise que, frequentemente, separa as fases de alavancagem e de desalavancagem conduz a danos adicionais nos balanços e prolongam o período de cura.

Graças, em parte, à investigação de Reinhart e Rogoff, sabemos hoje que uma alavancagem excessiva é insustentável e que o restabelecimento do balanço leva tempo. Em consequência, continuam as dúvidas e as questões relativamente a um eventual regresso à tendência anterior da crise para o PIB e, especialmente, para o emprego.

O que esta linha de pesquisa explicitamente não nos diz é que a desalavancagem vai restaurar o crescimento por si mesma. Ninguém acredita que o equilíbrio orçamental seja, em qualquer lado, o modelo completo de crescimento.

Observem a Europa do Sul. Do ponto de vista do crescimento e do emprego, a dívida pública e privada mascarou a ausência de crescimento da produtividade, queda da competitividade no sector transaccionável e um conjunto de deficiências estruturais subjacentes – incluindo a rigidez do mercado laboral, deficiências na educação e na formação de competências e um investimento insuficiente nas infra-estruturas. A dívida conduziu ao crescimento, criando uma procura agregada que não teria existido de outra maneira (o mesmo é verdade para os Estados Unidos e para o Japão, embora os pormenores sejam diferentes).

O governo não é o único actor em cena aqui. Quando o ciclo de desalavancagem se inicia, o sector privado começa a ajustar-se estruturalmente – um padrão visto claramente nos dados sobre o crescimento no sector transaccionável da economia norte-americana. Um limitado crescimento dos salários aumenta a competitividade e os recursos humanos e de capital que estão insuficientemente utilizados são reafectados.

A velocidade a que isto vai acontecer depende, em parte, da flexibilidade e do dinamismo do sector privado. Mas também está dependente da capacidade e da vontade do governo em ajudar a satisfazer as insuficiências na procura agregada e em seguir reformas e investimentos que impulsionem as perspectivas de crescimento a longo prazo.

Se a desalavancagem do sector público não é uma política de crescimento completa – e não é – por que é que é dada tanta atenção à austeridade orçamental e tão pouca ao crescimento e ao emprego?

Emergem aqui várias possibilidades – não mutualmente exclusivas. Uma é a de que algumas autoridades políticas pensam que o equilíbrio orçamental é, verdadeiramente, o principal pilar de uma estratégia de crescimento: desalavancar rapidamente e seguir em frente.

A crença de que o multiplicador orçamental é, em regra, baixo pode ter contribuído para subestimar os custos económicos no curto prazo de políticas de austeridade – e, assim, para as previsões persistentemente optimistas para o crescimento e para o emprego. Uma investigação recente do Fundo Monetário Internacional sobre a variabilidade dos multiplicadores orçamentais em determinados contextos levantou sérias dúvidas sobre o custo e a eficácia de uma consolidação orçamental acelerada.

As estimativas do multiplicador orçamental têm de ter como base uma hipótese ou um modelo que diga o que aconteceria na ausência de despesa pública de determinado tipo. Se a hipótese ou o modelo estiverem errados, também a estimativa o estará. O contra-factual precisa de ser tornado explícito e avaliado com prudência e dentro de um contexto.

Em alguns países com elevados níveis de dívida e com crescimento estagnado, os estímulos orçamentais podem aumentar o prémio de risco da dívida soberana e ser contraproducentes; outros têm uma maior flexibilidade. Os países variam amplamente no que diz respeito a danos nos balanços das famílias, o que afecta obviamente a sua capacidade para poupar – e, daí, o efeito multiplicador. A incerteza é a realidade e é necessário bom-senso.

Aparece, depois, a dimensão tempo. Se o investimento numa infra-estrutura, por exemplo, gera algum crescimento e emprego no curto e médio prazo e um maior crescimento sustentável no longo prazo, devemos exclui-lo apenas porque algumas estimativas do multiplicador são inferiores a um? Da mesma forma, se um estímulo orçamental tem os seus efeitos abafados porque quem recebe o rendimento está a poupar para restaurar os balanços familiares danificados, não é claro se vale a pena descontar o benefício de uma desalavancagem acelerada, mesmo se ele emergir, mais tarde, na procura doméstica.

Os políticos (e talvez os mercados financeiros) podem ter acreditado que os bancos centrais iriam servir como ponte para satisfazer as necessidades através de uma política monetária não convencional agressiva, desenhada para manter sob pressão as taxas de juro de curto e longo prazo. É certo que os bancos centrais desempenharam um papel essencial. Mas os bancos centrais já declararam que não têm os instrumentos políticos para acelerar o ritmo de recuperação económica.

Entre os custos e riscos das políticas de baixas taxas de juro está o regresso a um padrão de crescimento alavancado e a crescente incerteza relativamente aos limites da expansão do balanço de um banco central. Por outras palavras, será que o valor elevado dos activos, causado pelas baixas taxas a desconto, vai, de repente, voltar a cair a dado momento? Ninguém sabe.

Os países estão sujeitos a diferentes níveis de constrangimento orçamental, assumindo (especialmente no caso da Europa) um apetite diminuto por transferências além-fronteiras ilimitadas e incondicionais. Aqueles que têm alguma flexibilidade podem, e devem, usá-las para proteger os desempregados e os jovens, para acelerar a desalavancagem e para implementar reformas com o intuito de apoiar o crescimento e o emprego; as opções dos que não têm flexibilidade – e as suas perspectivas de crescimento a médio prazo – são mais restritivas.

Todos os países – e os decisores políticos – enfrentam escolhas difíceis no que diz respeito ao calendário da austeridade, ao risco do crédito soberano percepcionado, às reformas orientadas para o crescimento e à distribuição equitativa dos custos com o restabelecimento do crescimento. Até aqui, o desafio da partilha com os encargos, juntamente com modelos de crescimento ingénuos e incompletos, pode ter contribuído para o impasse e para a inacção.

A experiência pode ser um duro professor, apesar de necessário. O crescimento não vai ser restabelecido nem rápida nem facilmente. Talvez precisemos que a preocupação com a austeridade nos ensine o valor de uma agenda para o crescimento equilibrada.

In  Negócios online

Michael Spence, Nobel da Economia, é professor de Economia na Stern School of Business, da Universidade de Nova Iorque, e conselheiro no Instituto Hoover.
 
Copyright: Project Syndicate, 2013.
www.project-syndicate.org
Tradução: Diogo Cavaleiro